agriculture will also change with time, technology and resource availability. Not all socially desirable technologies will sufficiently benefit the private sector to cover costs of production and distribution of needed inputs and capital. Hybrid seed corn permitted pro- ducers and distributors to appropriate sufficient benefits to make it advantageous for them to produce and distribute the seed. The Plant Variety Protection Act of 1978 recognizes the difficulties of patenting and enforc- ing patents on biological materials (Schmid, forthcom- ing). It will not always be possible to devise laws that will permit private firms to recover developmental, pro- duction and distribution costs, even if the technologies involved are socially desirable. A specific example is the "minor use" program of agricultural chemicals for pest control. Here, the technologies will be more appropri- ately handled by Agricultural Experiment Stations and Extension Services. Considerable research is now being initiated by agricultural economists and sociologists on the roles of the public and private sectors. This research is timely. There are those who claim the private sector can hire the scientists to do the needed DISC, SM and PS research for developing all new technologies, thereby eliminating the need for public sector SM and PS research (Marshall, 1949). This argument presumes that private firms will benefit in creating, producing and distributing new technologies and that private firms will find it unprofitable to degrade the environment and con- taminate the food chain and to adversely affect the struc- ture of agriculture and society. International trade is becoming increasingly important for the United States and other nations. Technological progress will change our needs for fossil energy, phosphate, potash and other resources from abroad. Technological changes also influence the extent to which U.S. agriculture can penetrate foreign markets. The availability of inputs from international markets and of markets abroad for U.S. farm products helps determine the institutions and technologies we should generate. Thus, there are important interrelationships between in- ternational trade and both biotechnical and institutional research. These interrelationships pose a challenge for multidisciplinary teams of technical and social scientists. Needed are better long-term projections of the demand for U.S. farm products, the capacity of U.S. agriculture to produce in relation to the total U.S. economy and the world, and the availability of essential inputs from abroad. Research to maintain and increase the com- petitive position of U.S. farm products in international trade is of high priority and vital for the financial welfare of the nation. Issues relating to international trade, however, are complex. Trade and markets, at home and abroad, are subject to subsidies, protective tariffs, price ceilings and decisions of presumed strategic value. Models are available for making trade projections, but they are still relatively primitive. Much of the talent to build, maintain and improve projection models is in the universities. The Economic Research Service of the USDA is the logical operational home for projective modeling unless a state Agricultural Experiment Station is prepared to underwrite long-term maintenance costs and compete in selling outputs of such models in national and international markets. Redesign of capital and fiscal institutions for farms and range and forest resources is a challenge for multi- disciplinary SM research. Technological and institutional advances are so interrelated that changes should be simultaneously considered by biotechnical and social scientists, including agricultural economists. The public data system is in disarray. The federal data system for agriculture has deteriorated and become obsolete since World War II (Bonnen, 1977). State-level data systems for agriculture are far from uniform and, in many cases, inadequate. Multidisciplinary institu- tional research to improve the public data systems and information institutions for agriculture is critical. Such research would provide an improved knowledge base for setting science policy and research priorities for U.S. agriculture. Agricultural sector studies often simulate the operations of macroagricultural systems through time. The interest may be in a subsector, such as cotton, a national system or a global agricultural system. Projections for scenarios involving population growth, the availability of land, changes in yields and likely changes in real wages are useful. They are essential for studying long-term agricultural science policies and research priorities and for selecting specific projects. Policies are set on the basis of projections, ranging from hunches of people too specialized to see the whole picture to elaborate, com- puterized, formal models. Current procedures for mak- ing projections in science policies, in establishing priorities and in selecting research projects are not satisfactory. SM research by agricultural economists and systems scientists cooperating with scholars in agri- cultural technology, institutions and rural people is recommended (Rossmiller, ed., 1978). Rural Sociology Technical changes are being made to adjust to increased demand for land, higher water and energy costs and increasing real wages. Such changes restructure rural America. Other related forces are migration, changes in tastes and demography, and shifts in the location of off-farm employment associated with changing resource bases. The geographic patterns of pro- duction agriculture -will also change as computers in- crease the ability of farmers and companies to control and manage widely dispersed operations. SM research by social scientists, as well as biotechnical scientists, will