positively to a higher price. They persisted in maintain- ing the tax on palm oil (Johnson, 1969). On the other side of the world, the Malaysians were able to see the opportunity offered by the improved oil palm varieties. Their policies and institutional arrangements and their soils and climate were such that they could grow the improved varieties at a profit. Malaysia now has a thriving palm oil industry that earns substantial foreign exchange and provides a large amount of remunerative employment for Malaysians. The lesson is clear. Technological advance alone is not sufficient. It must be accompanied by institutions, policies and incentives that make it advantageous for the technology to be adopted. In the United States during World War II, there were deficiencies in labor for agriculture, and there were other wartime shortages. Rising costs made it dif- ficult for farmers to maintain and expand production to meet needs. Congress then passed and the president signed the so-called "Steagal Amendment" to establish and guarantee "necessary prices for three years after the cessation of W.W. II hostilities." This wise, forward-thinking legislation did much to provide incentives for farmers to expand production of com- modities necessary for the war effort. Included were soybeans, milk products, pork and other basic com- modities. Another example of an institutional change that favored productivity was the establishment of the Farm Credit Administration during the Great Depres- sion. From the mid-1930s on, this institution has done much to make credit available to farmers and to modernize American agriculture. Without this institu- tional change, American agriculture would not have developed the productive capacity it now has. History is replete with institutional and policy changes that have increased the productive capacity of U.S. agriculture. The current danger is that the reduced political power of farmers may combine with the concerns of "consumer interest" groups to reverse past U.S. agricultural policies and programs and move to a "cheaper food policy" with returns so low to farmers that they will not be able to generate the needed increases in production. We have benefited from past policies that have kept production up and food prices reasonable for everyone. Our food prices have probably been lower than they would have been under a cheap food policy capable of generating similar levels of output. Subject-Matter Research on Institutional and Related Changes Emphasis is on institutional and policy research that undergirds the generation, dissemination and adoption of technological change. SM research not related to technological change is omitted. Thus, much SM research on institutions important for the next half- century is not covered. Agricultural Economics SM research directly rele- vant to the generation and use of technological change includes that which should be pursued to accom- modate to the growing scarcity of land and water, more expensive energy, increasing real wages, a grow- ing and increasingly affluent U.S. population with demands for improved diets, and the need for foreign exchange. Also included is research on policies, pro- grams and institutions to facilitate the adoption of and obtain the best societal results from new technologies; and finally, research on the economics of developing the human capital needed to create, distribute and use new technologies (see later section on research on human development). Regulation of the use and adoption of high-technology inputs should be reviewed. Public regulations and laws to protect the environment, food chains and people may unduly retard the adoption of new technologies. It is not always clear whether regulations on the use of chemicals, biologicals and resources for specific pur- poses are, on balance, beneficial or detrimental. Economists should contribute to multidisciplinary SM research to provide assessments of the consequences of such regulations. Overuse of durables and expendables by farmers generally results in overuse of technology and the accumulation of government stocks or lower farm product prices and financial distress (Johnson and Quance, 1972). Overuse of such durables as machines reflecting the technology available at one time will later result in an obsolete agricultural production plant. Agricultural economists, political scientists, sociologists and technical agricultural scientists should design institutional arrangements, policies and pro- grams to prevent overuse of resources and determine the need for public expenditures to offset the undesirable consequences of overuse. Society, as well as farmers, loses when resources are overcommitted to agricultural production. The value of these resources cannot be recovered by either. The 1983 commodity and payment-in-kind (PIK) programs were designed to correct overuse. The costs and the short, intermediate and long-run consequences of the PIK program were not adequately researched. Thus the program has proven far more expensive than anticipated. Farming systems research (FSR) is too applied and multidisciplinary to be considered disciplinary, yet too general to be problem-solving. Agricultural economists and farm management specialist teams should estimate the profitability of alternative farming systems. They