changed. It is also interesting that the model accom- plishes this while the real price of farm products falls substantially. In the NIRAP model, U.S. agriculture does not inter- act with either the U.S. non-farm economy or with other economies in the world. However, it provides by 2030 for crop and livestock exports more than 50 percent above current levels. Further insights into the next half-century are derivable from the projections produced by the relatively new USDA/IIASA/MSU model, hereafter referred to as the USDA world model.' In that model, U.S. agriculture does interact with the U.S. non-farm economy and with other countries via an international trade linkage com- ponent. This permits the model to project exports and non-farm uses of farm products rather than estimating the consequences of assumed exports and non-farm uses. The model also provides more flexibility than NIRAP in projecting the development and use of currently less productive, more fragile soils; and the intensity of crop- ping mixes. This flexibility permits the model to tell us more than NIRAP does about technological advances needed to permit the cropping of soils not now cropped and to produce more crops per year and more intensive mixtures of crops. When the USDA world model is operated using scenarios similar to those used in the NIRAP projections discussed above, the results with respect to land use are essentially the same for 2030. Both models show similar increases in yields per acre and in land utilization. In- creased intensity of cropping mixes is explicit in the USDA world model and implied by the NIRAP model. However, in the USDA world model, U.S. grain exports run into competition in both domestic and world markets. Together, exports and domestic use increase rapidly in both models. Though exports are assumed in the NIRAP model, the U.S. non-farm sector competes in the USDA world model, probably unrealistically, with other countries for the use of coarse grains as in- dustrial feedstocks for producing gasohol and organic in- dustrial products. Domestic livestock producers also compete with foreign grain and livestock producers to expand production and exports. This increases U.S. exports of livestock products in the world model and cur- tails U.S. grain exports to such an extent that coarse grains are no longer exported in 2030. Though it is doubtful that U.S. trading partners would permit such an expansion of livestock production and exports, the USDA world and NIRAP models agree on the need for capacity to produce much more to meet substantial in- These helpful projections were made by Douglas Maxwell of the Economic Research Service (ERS) with the approval of John Lee, ERS administrator. creases in demand. Clearly a doubling of our capacity to produce agricultural output in the next 50 years is a reasonable target, even if we do not actually produce such levels of output. The world model was also used to project the conse- quences of a high level of world prosperity to see how exports and pressure on U.S. agricultural resources would be affected. In another attempt to see the conse- quences of stressing U.S. agriculture, the model was run using a scenario that reduced the yield-increasing effects of technological and other research by half. The results of these two analyses indicate that higher prosperity in the world would not expand the use of land in the United States in 2025 beyond the baseline projection of 436 million acres to meet export demands. The model's 2025 constraint of 450 million acres is not encountered. On the other hand, halving anticipated yield increases reduces acreage used because higher U.S. and world prices decrease U.S. exports and domestic use. Produc- tion abroad expands in response to the higher prices. (We should note that the halving of expected yield increases still generates yields in 2030 that are 32 to 40 percent above present levels.) To project events, accomplishments and progress in agricultural research and technology beyond a decade is fraught with many uncertainties. More important still is that the variables that determined the results are handled in scenarios because they are difficult to model and predict. In the above scenarios, levels of world pros- perity and yield increases were treated as unpredictable. Though yield increases may not be highly predictable, they can be influenced by such controllable factors as research appropriations; educational programs for en- trepreneurs, scientists and educators; and institutions and policies that make yield-increasing technology profitable or unprofitable. It is our conviction that the United States can manage the development of its agricultural technology, institu- tions, human and natural resources, and capital accumulations to make .it possible to attain the yields used in the NIRAP I and world model scenario. Some per acre yields for this scenario follow: Commodity Wheat, bu. Soybeans, bu. Grain Sorghum, bu. Barley, bu. Oats, bu. Corn, bu. Rough Rice, cwt. Seed Cotton, lbs. NIRAP I 1980 2030 32.8 30.0 70.4 49.4 55.7 106.9 48.8 485.0 59.8 45.0 112.5 78.9 77.1 178.2 74.6 692.0 World Model 1980 2030 33.5 30.6 57.5 47.3 53.8 100.0 47.6 480.0 63.5 47.0 97.5 80.3 78.8 200.0 60.0 620.0 Neither the NIRAP nor the world model projections