Annex 1 * Apart from the types of food deficits presented above, an additional type of food deficit resulting from market imbalances (market deficits or surpluses) may occur. In our model, market imbalances emerge if the internal market prices differ from the equilibrium prices. A market (-supply) deficit emerges if, for example due to price setting below the equilibrium price (po in Figure A-I, pm in Figure A-2) or due to a lack of foreign exchange to pay for food imports, effective demand exceeds domestic market supplies in the closed economy case or the total market supplies (domestic supplies + imports/ - exports) in the open economy case. If the market price is set above the equilibrium price, the volume of market supplies exceeds effective demand and market surpluses occur. Examples of market imbalances, resulting e.g. from official price settings different from the equilibrium price, and the implications for the food situation and the structure of food deficits are illustrated in Figure A-3d) and explained below. Description of cases of market imbalances: * If the market price is fixed below the equilibrium price (po in Figure A-1 or pm in Figure A-2), e.g. in order to make food affordable also for the poorer sections of the population, food demand would increase, hence the demand deficit would diminish. However, food supplies from domestic production as well as food imports (in the open economy case) would go down, leading to a widening of the production and supply deficits and the emergence of a market deficit: market supplies would be insufficient to cover the effective demand. A market price below the equilibrium price can only be maintained if complementary measures of market intervention are applied, e.g. concessional food imports (food imports at lower than world market prices, e.g. programme food aid). stock draw- downs, producer subsidies, or food rationing. All are frequently applied policy measures which will be discussed later. * If the market prices is set above the equilibrium price level, marketed food production will increase and the supply deficit diminish. However, at higher prices, less people will be able to afford the food they need, effective demand will go down and the overall demand deficit widen. As a result of the increased supplies and reduced demand, market surpluses would emerge: not all food offered on the market would be absorbed by effective demand. Higher than equilibrium prices can only be maintained if demand is increased by policy interventions, e.g. by building-up of food stocks and/or by consumer subsidies, or if supplies are reduced, e.g. by imposing restrictions on food import or by promoting food exports. These are, again, frequently applied policy measures. This scenario also shows that a country may well have market surpluses and even be a food exporter, yet food production, supplies and demand may be insufficient to meet total food requirements. In spite of abundant food supplies on the market, a large proportion of the population may lack the means to articulate their food needs as effective demand, and due to the lacking effective demand food production and supplies are insufficient to cover the requirements. - 268 -