Chapter 4 government objectives puts far too much emphasis on economic issues to be a complete explanation of the basis on which governments make decisions. Government policy is also heavily influenced by social and political concerns. It does, however, encompass all the main elements of macroeconomic policy, and as shown in the figure above, this in turn influences who can achieve their food requirements and how. In each country, the government will pursue its own balance between all these different policy elements, according to its own political philosophy: the importance it puts on its own role as a provider of goods and services; the priority it puts on the welfare of different sectors of the population; and its own self-interest. When governments change, these views will also change, and along with that, economic policy. However, governments and their economic policies do not exist in a vacuum. External and domestic economic shocks can make existing policies unsustainable, or extremely difficult to maintain. Governments may be forced to make abrupt changes in policy, which in turn may have a damaging impact on the food security of its citizens. The next section examines the macroeconomic shocks and world trends which have affected developing countries in particular, as a context for further discussion of the macroeconomy and food security. 1.2 Macroeconomic shocks, international economic trends and food security Many developing countries, amongst them some of the poorest in the world, have laced problems of increasingly unsustainable structural imbalances since the mid-1970s. These imbalances have developed in their external accounts, or balance of payments, and often also in their internal accounts, or public sector budget. In the short run, many countries responded to these imbalances by borrowing on international markets, which was made easier by the excess liquidity in international markets following the oil price shocks of the 1970s. This was only an appropriate response if either the government felt that the imbalance resulted from a temporary shock which would soon be reversed, or the economy itself had strong automatic adjustment mechanisms which would correct the imbalance. However, where the economy had a more rigid internal structure, policy changes were necessary to encourage increases in economic activity thus creating income and foreign exchange flows which would repay the borrowing. In the absence of this a country could very easily sink into a negative spiral of increasing debt and rising debt service payments and, in fact, this has been the experience of many poorer countries since the mid-1970s. If a country borrows to maintain its consumption and investment levels over the medium term, this excess demand will, in itself, create a balance of payments deficit, as it sustains the demand for traded and non-traded goods in excess of the production levels in the economy. This has two effects. It increases the amount of imports and forces up the price of non-traded goods. This distorts domestic price levels and biases production towards non-traded goods. In most countries, this translates into a bias against the agriculture and food producing sectors. Imbalances can be caused by macroeconomic shocks or by the continuous pursuit of domestic policies which fail to achieve internal balance (full employment and price stability), such as governments persisting in running high budget deficits. Major macroeconomic shocks can be both external or internal in source. Combinations of some or all of these causes of structural imbalance have been faced by many developing countries in the past few decades. - 109-