to-face relations and social pressures they would generate. As supervision at Comilla became relaxed and corrupt, as basic level groups were expanded and reformed so that face-to-face relations in the group setting became less important, the programs at Comilla became more controlled by the elite farmers.1 It is often the case, however, that a larger organization is re- quired, either to obtain potential economies of scale (e.g., for purchasing trucks, installing electricity systems) or to include all potential "free riders" (e.g., a large irrigation system). As the group gets large enough so that an individual's actions no longer perceptibly affect the group's fortunes, and as group social pressures are reduced, some combination of personal incentives, threats of coercion, and external supervision seem necessary to assure participation.2 Equally important, some organizational format is needed to tie to- gether small face-to-face groups of farmers into larger units that can provide appropriate economies of scale. In Taiwan, for example, the farmers' associations are organized from smaller village-based groups. Moreover, they have responsibility for tax collection and monopoly over fertilizer sales. Thus, all farmers were compelled to deal with the farmers' associations, even if they did not join. In addition, they had to join to take advantage of credit, extension, and marketing services. 1Harry Blair, The Elusiveness of Equity: Institutional Approaches to Rural Development in Bangladesh (Ithaca: Cornell Rural Development Committee, 1974), pp. 45-61. 2Mancur Olson, The Logic. 3Benedict Stavis, Rural Local Governance and Agricultural Development in Taiwan (Ithaca: Cornell Rural Development Committee, 1974).