Finally, it may not be rational for an individual to participate in group activities which will benefit him. Indeed, if he can avoid the cost and obligations of group activities but share in the benefits with- out undermining group functioning, he obviously is rational. Whether and how these problems can be overcome depends on the character of the group in question. Some successful group activities are based on the indigenous voluntary groups which exist in rural societies -- kinship, religion, labor exchange, credit associations, etc. Size is im- portant; particularly if the group is small enough so that each individual's actions perceptibly influence the group's fortunes, the internal social pressures for cohesive action can be strong.2 But the group needs to be large enough to generate economics of scale. Perhaps the optimal size for such voluntary interaction is around 30 35 people -- the size of the Chinese work team,3 of successful midwestern food cooperatives,4 or of groups in Mexico's Puebla Project.5 These social pressures were utilized at Comilla, where the credit associations were required to have weekly meetings to maximize the face- Mancur Olson, The Logic. 2Mancur Olson, The Logic..., pp. 53-57. Carl Riskin, "Maoism and Motivation: Work Incentives in China," in Victor Nee and James Peck, eds., China Uninterrupted Revolutions From 1840-to the Present (New York: Pantheon, 1973), p. 431. Ron Cotterill, The Social Economics of Participatory Consumer Cooperatives (East Lansing: Michigan Sate University, Department of Agricultural Economics, Agricultural Economics Report No. 369, December 1979), p. 31. 5Allen Jedlicka, Organization for Rural Development, p. 74