51 of the economy. However, this induction is not automatic. Induction requires institutions, of which an extension system is one, to convey specific technological needs of various producers to the researchers.1 If the extension system does not provide feedback about the needs of small, subsistence farmers, it is unlikely that appropriate technologies will be induced for them. In the absence of such pressures, the innovations that are induced are more likely to be suited to the needs of large aggressive farmers, who can influence the research system directly by going to a university to talk with scientists or indirectly, through a Ministry of Agriculture to which they have access.2 The farmers with cash crops crucial for foreign exchange earnings (rubber in Malaysia, cocoa in Ghana, coffee, sugar and coconuts in the other countries) seem to have little problem conveying their needs to research institutes. But the perspectives and needs of the poor, limited-resource, subsistence farmer, unable to purchase machinery and chemicals, rarely inform the work of research units. Thus, any extension system, and especially one designed to serve the needs of rural poor, needs to emphasize feedback, particularly from small farmers. The bias towards overemphasizing communication to the farmer, instead of from the farmer, has several sources. First, it reflects the structure of control within the extension system. If the extension system is controlled and financed by farmers, the agents usually are responsive to interest and needs of farmers, 1Alain de Janvry, "Social Structure and Biased Technical Change in Argentine Agriculture," in Hans Binswanger and Vernon Ruttan, Induced Innovations (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1978), p. 311. 2Rene Benalcazar R., "New Techniques, Agricultural Extension Services."