40 Nevertheless, the program had some successes also. Some smaller farmers were able to buy tube wells, and many landless and near landless were able to get into dairying, for which land ownership is not a pre- requisite. 2. Decentralization To guard against the dangers of centralized programs, many writers advocate that extension systems be decentralized and controlled directly by farmers. The logic of the decentralized system is that it will assure that extension programs fit more accurately local needs, perceptions, values, knowledge, and natural conditions. It is less likely to be controlled by urban or bureaucratic needs. There are several examples of such organizations. In most states of the United States, county level farmers' organizations have a major influence on the hiring, firing, and salaries of county extension agents. In Taiwan, extension agents are hired by township farmers'.associa- tions. Their salaries are directly related to the profitability of the farmers' associations, and this is somewhat (but not entirely) related to productivity of agriculture in the township.1 Thus, the agent is presumed to have a strong incentive towards helping to increase local farm productivity. In Finland, township councils control extension work. In mainland China also, people who perform an extension function are hired directly by communes and brigades. In Israel, farmers' representatives make up an advisory board which reviews the annual work plan of the extension system. In all these cases, there may be central guidelines concerning salaries, educational qualifications, etc., but farmers and Benedict Stavis, Rural Local Governance and Agricultural Development in Taiwan (Ithaca: Cornell Rural Development Committee, 1974), p. 93. 2 Raanan Weitz and Arshalom Rokach, Agricultural Development: Planning and Implementation, An Israeli Case Study (New York: Praeger, 1968), pp. 391-392.