25 innovative got only 6 percent of the extension visits. Other surveys in Kenya agree.2 Likewise, even in socialist Tanzania, with strong rhetorical pressures toward equality, one survey showed that 59 percent of wealthy farmers had a high level of extension contact, while only 29 percent of poor farmers had such contacts.3 In one locality of Northern Nigeria, the local elites had reasonably good knowledge about extension activity, while most farmers had negligable informa- tion.4 Thus, the normal pattern is that extension services concentrate on services for the larger, progressive farmers. This unequal access to extension services can have different consequences for long term trends in income distribution and social structure, depending on the character of institutions and on the markets. In many countries this tendency of extension to help primarily the rural wealthy reinforces underlying economic, political, and social trends. With profits coming from improved technology, large progressive'farmers may buy out their neighbors who are unable to meet the costs of commercial farming, particularly if land ceiling restrictions are lax. Some small farmers, and particularly their sons, may have no choice but to become land- less laborers or migrants to cities. Thus a knowledge gap between the rich and poor reinforces an economic gap.5 These tendencies will David Leonard, pp. 125-177. Joseph Ashcroft, Niels Roling, Joseph Kariuki, and Fred Chege, Extension and the Forgotten Farmer (Wageningen: Afdelingen voor Sociate Wetenschappen aan de Landbouwhogeschool, 1973), p. 31. James DeVries, "Agricultural Extension and the Development of Ujamaa Villages in Tanzania: Toward a Diological Agricultural Ex- tension Model," Ph.D. dissertation, University of Wisconsin, Madison, 1978, p. 167. Peter Matlon, "The Size, Distribution, Structure, and Deter- minants of Personal Income Among Farmers in the North of Nigeria," Cornell Agricultural Economics Ph.D. dissertation, 1977, p. 390. On next page.