23 for urban classes to ally with the narrow rural elites. In such a situation, most of the benefits of development will go to the cities, but the rural elites will also prosper. The rural poor will remain clients of the rural elites, and are tempted to migrate into the urban Tabor force.. Certain features in the methodology of extension work are congruent with, and reinforce, such a political alliance. Analysis of the activities of extension workers in many countries shows that they tend to focus attention on the few "progressive farmers," who have adequate resources to afford and risk new technologies, and who are interested in selling (and buying) more. Such an empirical find- ing is often'converted to a prescription. It is presumed (sometimes accurately) that knowledge will "spread" from these "community leaders" to other farmers, and that the benefits will eventually "trickle down" to the poor, through more efficient technology, more jobs, or lower food prices. (There is, however, a risk. The "progressive farmer" may, for ethnic, cultural, psychological, or historical reasons, turn out to be someone who is not trusted or respected in the community. In such a case, there may be very little spread affect.)2 From an administrative point of view, it is convenient for extension agents to work with large farmers. To have an innovation utilized on 100 hectares of land, it is far easier to convince one farmer with 100 hectares than to convince 100 farmers with only one hectare. If the extension agent is judged by his success in extending an innovation over a wide area, he will not waste his time with small farmers. In addition, the extension agent, often coming 1Michael Lipton, "Towards a Theory of Land Reform," in David Lehmann, ed., Agrarian Reform and Agrarian Reformism (London: Faber and Faber, 1974), pp. 311-312. 2Everett M. Rogers, with F. Floyd Shoemaker, Communication of Innovations (New York: Free Press, 1971), p. 5.