1981). Setting goals and objectives is outside the farmer's purview when the farm has to respond to resource scarcity. Farming is reactive when access to inputs is limited. When access is even more limited because of gender and differential power, often caused by a colonial history (Etienne and Leacock, 1980), farming becomes even more reactive. Farm management research in the United States has assumed that the farmer is male, and the successful farmer "involves his wife as a meaningful helpmate in his business and community affairs" (Buller, 1976:4). The assumption behind farm management research is that farming is a family enterprise and is only successful when this occurs. This same assumption is held in FSR. The. difference is thatwe realizethat in theThird Worldthe farmer will sometimes be female and, in certain situations (particularly when we are talking about marginal farmers producing subsistence crops) the farmer is more likely to be female than male. The realization of who does the farming versus who is getting the agricultural information is crucial. This disjuncture must be taken into account as we try to overcome our cultural biases in approaching developing processes. Farm management in the United States arose as farming became more commercialized and capitalistic (Case and Williams, 1957:5). This commer- cialization and capitalist nexis is very important to remember when we contrast FSR&D in the Third World with farm management in the First. Farming systems in the Third World (particularly those of small farmers) very often have a subsistence basis rather than a commercialized basis. Many of the economic structures into which the farms are placed are pre-capitalist rather than capitalist. Third World farms are linked to the capitalist market in three ways: the sale of their products, the sale of their labor, and the inputs they purchase. Linkage through the sale of crops is most common in the United States. Yet, the majority of the crops very often are not sold, but are consumed on the farm or bartered locally, particularly in parts of Africa and Latin America. The more usual way in which the small farm in the Third World is linked to the market economy-that is to say to the world system-is through the sale of labor. The farm family becomes semi-proletarianized, with one part of the 3fmily maintaining the farm and production, and another part oa the -fmily selling their labor in the market (Goodman and Redclift, 1982). The people who sell their labor tend to be those who command the highest wages because cash takes priority. These people tend to be males (Leon, 1982). This leaves women in charge of production of subsistence crops-the wage foods-that are the backbone of the economy and, yet, these crops are the least valued within that society. Men will take jobs, generally through temporary migration (Friedman, 1978; Laite, 1977) and will work in the harvest of cash crops, particularly export crops (Homen- de Melo and Zockun, 1977). Export crops include cotton, coffee, cacao, and sugar. The men may also be involved in the construction booms that accompany petroleum development, particularly in petroleum countries. For instance, in Equador and in Nigeria, people will migrate to the urban centers to provide a low-wage, construction labor force. Employment in extractive industries, particularly mining, can also be the first major link with the monetary economy. In much of southern Africa, the movement of males to work in the mines has left farms in the hands of females.