Despite important similarities between FSR and the early forms of farm management research, differences are apparent in the treatment of motivations and the flexibility of recommendations emerging from the analysis of.existing farming systems. Farm management research assumed that successful farmers had to be thrifty, hard-working, profit maximizers. They would prosper, expand, and should be emulated. As late as 1947, farm management was being defined as "the act of judiciously and skillfully managing a farm" (Boss and Pond, 1947). Further, much of farm management literature tended to be prescriptive in nature, indicating what farmers should do to be successful rather than trying to understand the logic of the fanning practices that the mass of farmers were using (Gilbert, et al, 1980: 121-122). Thus, where prescription might work in the United States because assumptions about goals could be taken for granted, this cannot be the case in developing countries, particularly among marginal farmers. We cannot assume that people want to expand, to get larger to maximize profit. Further, we must realize that one farmer expanding pushes another off the land, where even fewer chances of generating income can be found. Families on Third World, small, marginal farms seek to minimize risk. Often people will want to use any surplus generated for off-farm investments, instead of reinvesting them in the farm, which has been the assumption of profit use in the United States. In the Third World, surplus generated is used rationally for ceremonial consumption which serves to further unite the community--to ward off the possibilities of divisions that would weaken everyone as the whole was weakened. Surplus may be invested to send children to school. These children ultimately work off the farm, where chances of higher return to the investment are available. Farming systems research attempts to integrate differing goals into research programs aimed at marginal, small farmers. Current farm management in the United States has as its goal the greatest continuing profit (3uller, 1976:1). This assumption for small farms in developing countries cannot be taken for granted. Other goals may be motivating the farm family, and these goals must be recognized and caken into account wnen technology is recommended, research is done, and results are assessed. In farm management, as currently practiced in the United States, the assumption is that profitability is the goal. Profitability has the advantage of giving us something easy to measure. Weber called it formal rationality necessary for a modern economy (Weber, 1947:184-186). But, many Third World marginal farms are not part of the modern economy. Profitability can be measured by reducing inputs and outputs to dollars and cents, which can be easily subtracted from one another. This single summary measure makes for easy compar- isons between farms. In developing countries, because we cannot assume that the highest continuous profitability is the goal, we have to devise other measures of success. We can no longer reduce all inputs and outputs neatly and carefully to economic terms. In the United States, early Farm Management Research (FMR) assumed that a better cropping mix and more judicious use of resources would improve the farm family's welfare-and maintain soil productivity-through higher sustainable incomes.