approach is common in transportation literature (e.g. Beilock and Shonkwiler, Binkley and Harrar, Ferguson and Glorfeld, and Perkins). The price necessary to bring forth the services depends upon the direct or variable input costs (INP) and the opportunity costs of alternative uses (PA). INP will depend upon such factors as the quantity to be hauled (Q), the dis- tance (D), and the quality of service (QUAL): (1) PT = PT (INP(Q, D, QUAL,), PA) Assuming that fuel efficiencies, speeds, and labor costs are similar across trucks, distance (D) is a reasonable proxy for running or on-the-road costs. As virtually all of the vehicles had fully loaded, 42 to 45-foot refrigerated trailers, the quantities carried (Q) can be assumed to be constant. Moreover, all of the produce and ornamentals require similar care in handling. Therefore, the major observable variations in service quality (QUAL) per trip were the number of pickups (PKUP) and drops (DROPS). Unfortunately, the promptness of service as represented by the queue length or the amount of excess capacity offered was not observable. However, following DeVany and Saving (1977), in a competitive market the time- sensitivity of the commodities may be substituted for queue length. In this analysis, time-sensitivity is proxied by the average per day loss in cargo value calculated as the per hun- dredweight farm level price divided by days of storage life (DAYLOSS).3,4 DAYLOSS would also serve as a proxy for the level of risk inherent with each cargo. This follows because DAYLOSS is, essentially, the level of liability (value) times an index of the probability of a claim. The inverse of shelf life indicates sensitivity to delays in transit and rough han- dling, as produce becomes more susceptible to bruising and rot as it ripens. Therefore, while the expedited service hypothe- sis is viewed by the author as likely to be the most important unobserved service, it must be acknowledged that the effect of insurance costs is not separable in the analysis.