band radios. Under such near-classical competitive conditions one would not expect chronic nonpayment for additional services (pickups and drops) or that one type of carrier would be con- sistently favored over another due to the ability to secure more complete market information. The conclusions reached by the Transportation Research Center study team were arrived at largely from informal discus- sions with carriers, brokers, and receivers rather than by the use of statistical techniques. The theoretically surprising nature of their conclusions led to a reexamination of these issues in this current study. In the remainder of this section, largely nonempirical work addressing the three objectives of this study is dis- cussed. This is done to provide a rationale for the approach which was taken and to familiarize the reader with the reasons why these issues are of concern. 1. How rates change over distance In Figure 1 are presented three types of distance-rate relationships: flat, linear, and less-than proportional or tapering. Flat schedules are usually attributable to some form of institutional influence. The U.S. Mail First Class Service is a prime example. Letters are transported anywhere in the nation for the same charge. Linear schedules are what one would expect to find. Once the "fixed" or distance-unrelated costs, such as pickup and delivery, are accounted for (in the intercept) there may be little reason to suppose that driving the 100th mile would be any less costly than the 1000th mile. However, several researchers have noted that rates for regu- lated motor carriers exhibit tapers over distance (Bresseler and King, Pegrum, and Lockin). There are three principal rea- sons for explaining rate tapers. First, different equipment may be employed for hauls of different lengths (Bresseler and